INSIGHTS FROM:Daniel Murphy
WRITTEN BY:Jenny M. Abel
Despite this theoretical consensus, there is little evidence that government spending actually raises interest rates in the United States or other advanced economies. To the contrary, evidence from the U.S. and U.K. suggests that government spending lowers interest rates.2
INTEREST RATE RESPONSE TO FISCAL STIMULUS: IRRF
Darden Professor Daniel Murphy and colleagues formerly or currently associated with UVA — Jorge Miranda-Pinto, Kieran James Walsh and Eric R. Young — propose a new theory to help explain how interest rates can actually fall in response to increases in government spending. They first document how interest rates respond across high-income countries. Consistent with prior evidence, they find that the interest rate response to fiscal stimulus (what they refer to as the IRRF) is negative in the U.S. The IRRF is also negative in about half of high-income countries that are members of the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD). It is positive in the other half.
Why is the IRRF positive in some counties (consistent with standard theory) but not in others? To address this questions, they examine a range of country-level factors and find that high consumer debt and high inequality are associated with a lower IRRF. Their result is especially surprising, since prior theoretical work suggests that high debt should be associated with additional pressure on credit markets in response to government spending and a higher IRRF.
To explain this otherwise puzzling relationship, the authors appeal to a companion paper, “A Model of Expenditure Shocks,”3 which proposes a model whereby many high-debt, low-income households save rather than spend additional income. They show that such a model can explain household’s consumption and income patterns.
THE RESEARCH
Murphy and his colleagues looked at data spanning two decades, primarily from countries in the OECD, supplemented by additional data samples. They specifically zeroed in on the relationship between IRRF and income inequality measures for each country. The measure of inequality is the ratio of the income of the richest tenth of the population to the income of the poorest tenth — figures provided by the OECD. The researchers then took the average of this ratio over the 2001–13 period, showing the United States to be the most unequal country, while Denmark had the greatest equality.
The researchers laid these data side by side with the government bond yields over the period 1987–20074 to reveal an inverse relationship between income inequality and IRRF (as measured by government bond yield response to fiscal shocks). In other words, in countries with high income inequality, fiscal stimuli (like tax rebates) generate smaller increases in interest rates than in countries with greater income equality. A little more than half of the 28 studied countries had a negative interest-rate response to fiscal stimulus.
A NEW THEORY
Why might the behavior of high-debt households matter for understanding the IRRF? The authors develop a general equilibrium model — one in which many aspects of the economy are interrelated — to formalize the intuition.
In their model:
- Higher inequality causes more low-income households to take on debt to afford basic consumption needs.
- When the government spends, it provides income for these low-income households, in hopes they (and others) will spend.
- The low-income/high-debt households use the additional income to pay off the debt.
- By providing income to the low-income households, the government uses resources (from taxes, which include households that do spend more).
- This redistribution of income helps relax credit markets.
- This, they propose, is the explanation for why countries with high debt and inequality have a lower IRRF.
On its own, this mechanism does not explain why interest rates actually fall in some countries. For that, the authors appeal to insights from some authors’ other theoretical work on the existence of slack — that is, underutilized resources — in the economy.[5] The authors show that combining the redistribution effect with theories featuring economic slack can explain the negative IRRF.
Daniel Murphy co-authored “Saving Constraints, Debt, and the Credit Market Response to Fiscal Stimulus” with Jorge Miranda-Pinto of the University of Queensland, Kieran James Walsh of the University of California, Santa Barbara, and Eric R. Young of the University of Virginia.
- 1.See for example, Jared Bernstein, “Despite All the Stimulus, the U.S. Economy Is Slowing. What’s Up With That?” The Washington Post, 26 July 2019, http://www.washingtonpost.com/outlook/2019/07/26/despite-all-stimulus-us-economy-is-slowing-whats-up-with-that or Patricia Cohen, “US Growth at Slowest Since 2016, Complicating Trump’s Pitch,” The New York Times, 30 January 2020, https://www.nytimes.com/2020/01/30/business/economy/gdp-numbers.html.
- 2.Daniel Murphy and Kieran James Walsh, “Government Spending and Interest Rates,” 10 October 2018, Darden Business School Working Paper No. 2634141, http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2634141.
- 3.Jorge Miranda-Pinto, Daniel Murphy, Kieran James Walsh and Eric R. Young, “A Model of Expenditure Shocks,” 3 January 2020, Darden Business School Working Paper No. 3455745, http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3455745.
- 4.They stopped at 2007 to avoid introducing structural breaks associated with the global financial crisis.
Original post https://alertarticles.info